Showing 1 - 10 of 19
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10011757803
We use evidence from the Second Reform Act, introduced in the United Kingdom in 1867, to analyze the impact on electoral outcomes of extending the vote to the unskilled urban population. Exploiting the sharp change in the electorate caused by franchise extension, we separate the effect of reform...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010698770
Followers wish to coordinate their actions in an uncertain environment. A follower would like his action to be close to some ideal (but unknown) target; to reflect his own idiosyncratic preferences; and to be close to the actions of others. He learns about his world by listening to leaders....
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010604024
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10013190864
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012086645
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005408944
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005413671
In a Lucas-Phelps island economy, an island has access to many informative signals about demand conditions. Each signal incorporates both public and private information: the correlation of a signal׳s realizations across the economy determines its publicity. If information sources differ in...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10011120388
In a plurality-rule election, a group of voters must coordinate behind one of two challengers in order to defeat a disliked status quo. Departing from existing work, the support for each challenger must be inferred from the private observation of informative signals. The unique equilibrium...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010970181
In the context of a "beauty-contest" coordination game (in which pay-offs depend on the quadratic distance of actions from an unobserved state variable and from the average action), players choose how much costly attention to pay to various informative signals. Each signal has an underlying...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010575575