Showing 1 - 10 of 10
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012131562
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10001764236
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10001797799
Campbell, Hilscher, and Szilagyi (2008) show that firms with a high probability of default have significantly low average future returns. We show that there is a large overlap between stocks classified as high default risk, and those that are likely to produce extremely high returns over the...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10013109026
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009719760
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10003916318
We use a sample of option prices, and the method of Bakshi, Kapadia and Madan (2003), to estimate the ex ante higher moments of the underlying individual securities' risk-neutral returns distribution. We find that individual securities' volatility, skewness, and kurtosis are strongly related to...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10013116546
In Merton (1987), idiosyncratic risk is priced in equilibrium as a consequence of incomplete diversification. We modify his model to allow the degree of diversification to vary with average idiosyncratic volatility. This simple recognition results in a state-dependent idiosyncratic risk premium...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012903618
In Merton (1987), idiosyncratic risk is priced in equilibrium as a consequence of incomplete diversification. We modify his model to allow the degree of diversification to vary with average idiosyncratic volatility. This simple recognition results in a state-dependent idiosyncratic risk premium...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012598449
In Merton (1987), idiosyncratic risk is priced in equilibrium as a consequence of incomplete diversification. We modify his model to allow the degree of diversification to vary with average idiosyncratic volatility. This simple recognition results in a state-dependent idiosyncratic risk premium...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012997911