Showing 1 - 10 of 11
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005408702
A social choice function may or may not satisfy a desirable property depending on its domain of definition. For the same reason, different conditions may be equivalent for functions defined on some domains, while not in other cases. Understanding the role of domains is therefore a crucial issue...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10011049708
When members of a voting body exhibit single peaked preferences, pair-wise majority voting equilibria (Condorcet winners) always exist. Moreover, they coincide with the median(s) of the votersʼ most preferred alternatives. This important fact is known as the median voter result. Variants of it...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10011049747
The rule of k names can be described as follows: given a set of candidates for office, a committee chooses k members from this set by voting, and makes a list with their names. Then a single individual from outside the committee selects one of the listed names for the office. Different variants...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10008865881
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005408712
We consider the problem of efficiently sharing water from a river among a group of satiable agents. Since each agent's benefit function exhibits a satiation point, the environment can be described as a cooperative game with externalities. We show that the downstream incremental distribution is...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005409134
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005409271
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005413603
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005413633
In one-dimensional environments with single-peaked preferences we consider social welfare functions satisfying Arrow's requirements, i.e. weak Pareto and independence of irrelevant alternatives. When the policy space is a one-dimensional continuum such a welfare function is determined by a...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005413702