Showing 1 - 10 of 161
The common choice theory in economics is based on the assumption that an individual is defined in terms of a binary preference relation. This preference relation is defined over alternatives without taking into account menu dependence and, in particular, freedom of choice or, more generally, the...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005369386
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005369415
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005370752
The merit of approval voting has been widely discussed in the past 25 years. The distinct property of this rule is the extent of flexibility it allows; any voter can approve as many alternatives/candidates as he wishes. Nevertheless, this advantage is the very reason for two drawbacks of...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005370855
Many voting rules and, in particular, the plurality rule and Condorcet-consistent voting rules satisfy the simple-majority decisiveness property. The problem implied by such decisiveness, namely, the universal disregard of the preferences of the minority, can be ameliorated by applying unbiased...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010861924
This study shows that distortion of probabilities is a possible reason for rent under-dissipation in contests with relatively small number of participants. Such distortion may also result, however, in over-dissipation of the contested rent. Focusing on contests with homogeneous contestants and...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005071717
The Borda rule is known to be the least vulnerable scoring rule to Condorcet inconsistency, Saari (2000). Such inconsistency occurs when the Condorcet winner (the alternative which is preferred to any other alternative by a simple majority) is not selected by the Borda rule. This note exposes...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005597798
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005752962
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005155474
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009327380