Showing 1 - 10 of 59
In cases where legislators represent districts that vary in population, the design of fair legislative voting rules requires an understanding of how the number of votes cast by a legislator is related to a measure of her influence over collective decisions. We provide three new characterizations...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010821196
Assume that voters must choose between voting yes (Y) and voting no (N) on three propositions on a referendum. If the winning combination is NYY on the first, second, and third propositions, respectively, the paradox of multiple elections is that NYY can receive the fewest votes of the 23 = 8...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005369244
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005409363
We introduce some new voting rules based on a spatial version of the median known as the mediancentre, or Fermat-Weber point. Voting rules based on the mean include many that are familiar: the Borda Count, Kemeny rule, approval voting, etc. (see Zwicker (2008a,b)). These mean rules can be...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10011065213
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005596459
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005605690
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005605763
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005826809
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005826881
Symmetric (3,2) simple games serve as models for anonymous voting systems in which each voter may vote "yes," abstain, or vote "no," the outcome is "yes" or "no," and all voters play interchangeable roles. The extension to symmetric (j,2) simple games, in which each voter chooses from among j...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10008483508