Showing 1 - 10 of 233
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009545825
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009237579
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012223982
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10011741994
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010007727
A long tradition suggests a fundamental distinction between situations of risk, where true objective probabilities are known, and unmeasurable uncertainties where no such probabilities are given. This distinction can be captured in a Bayesian model where uncertainty is represented by the agent's...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010368245
Dispersion in retail prices of identical goods is inconsistent with the standard model of price competition among identical firms, which predicts that all prices will be driven down to cost. One common explanation for such dispersion is the use of a loss-leader strategy, in which a firm prices...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10011599412
In the reputation literature, players have \emph{commitment types} which represent the possibility that they do not have standard payoffs but instead are constrained to follow a particular plan. In this paper, we show that arbitrary commitment types can emerge from incomplete information about...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10011599566
Predictions under common knowledge of payoffs may differ from those under arbitrarily, but finitely, many orders of mutual knowledge; Rubinstein's (1989)Email game is a seminal example. Weinstein and Yildiz (2007) showed that the discontinuity in the example generalizes: for all types with...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012215306
Predictions under common knowledge of payoffs may differ from those under arbitrarily, but finitely, many orders of mutual knowledge; Rubinstein's (1989) Email game is a seminal example. Weinstein and Yildiz (2007) showed that the discontinuity in the example generalizes: for all...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012637367